244x Filetype PDF File size 0.18 MB Source: www.fao.org
Social Protection and Agriculture in Ethiopia Stephen Devereux and Bruce Guenther Institute of Development Studies, University of Sussex Country case study paper prepared for a review commissioned by the FAO on ‘Social Protection and Support to Small Farmer Development’ 30 November 2007 1 Introduction...........................................................................................................................2 2 Agriculture and social protection in Ethiopia: complementarity or convergence? .................3 3 ‘Land politics’ and social protection in Ethiopia.....................................................................4 4 Agricultural development strategies in Ethiopia ....................................................................5 5 Ethiopia’s Food Security Programme....................................................................................6 5.1 Productive Safety Net Programme (PSNP)...............................................................6 5.1.1 Direct linkages – PSNP public works.................................................................8 5.1.2 Indirect linkages – investment of PSNP transfers..............................................9 5.2 Household Extension Packages (HEP)...................................................................10 5.3 Voluntary Resettlement Programme (VRP).............................................................11 6 Other social protection interventions for Ethiopian smallholders.........................................12 6.1 Disaster prevention and risk management..............................................................12 6.2 Weather–indexed drought insurance.......................................................................13 6.4 Ethiopian Commodity Exchange (ECEX)................................................................14 7 Conclusion..........................................................................................................................15 References: Ethiopia case study..................................................................................................17 List of Tables Table 1 Investment uses of PSNP cash transfers for investment, by income quintile..............9 List of Figures Figure 1 Objectives of Ethiopia’s Productive Safety Net Programme........................................7 Figure 2 Ethiopia’s proposed integrated drought risk management plan.................................13 Page 1 of 18 1 Introduction Agriculture and social protection in Ethiopia are inextricably interconnected. Smallholder farming is the dominant livelihood activity for the majority of Ethiopians, but it is also the major source of vulnerability to poverty, food insecurity and their often fatal consequences – chronic malnutrition, premature mortality, recurrent famines. Ethiopian farmers have been the recipients of enormous volumes of food aid and other humanitarian assistance over recent decades, to such an extent that emergency relief has become institutionalised within government structures and donor agency country programmes. The discourse surrounding the complex relationship between agriculture and social protection in Ethiopia can be approached from either perspective. From the agricultural policy perspective, the government’s unshakeable belief in the centrality of farming as the backbone and potential source of growth for the Ethiopian economy is mirrored by its almost ideological view that land is the ultimate ‘safety net’ for rural households, who should therefore be protected against losing their access to land – by being prevented from selling it. From the social protection perspective, awareness that able-bodied farmers are the main ‘beneficiaries’ of safety nets and humanitarian food aid has fuelled the government’s visceral fear of creating ‘dependency’ in rural communities, which in turn explains the predominance of public works projects as their preferred delivery mechanism for food aid, as well as recent shifts in safety net thinking towards cash transfers rather than food aid, with predictable multi-annual transfers expected to lead to ‘graduation’ within a defined time period. The discourse on agriculture and social protection (or ‘safety nets’) in Ethiopia might start at a high level of ideological rhetoric and theoretical abstraction, but it plays itself out in real-world policy choices that attempt to find a balance between maximising opportunities and minimising risks. This policy dilemma can be succinctly stated: in a high-risk environment, should you adopt conservative strategies that minimise risk but keep people poor, or push aggressively for growth and ‘grow your way out of poverty’? In the past, the Government has apparently been satisfied with the former approach, but recent policy statements, specifically the ‘Plan for Accelerated and Sustained Development to End Poverty’ (PASDEP), signalled its impatience with the evident failure of this strategy, and embarked on a significant and ambitious shift towards agricultural commercialisation for income generation and wealth creation at household and national levels. Adopted around the same time, the ‘Productive Safety Net Programme’ (PSNP) represents an impatience with decades of food aid that have failed even to sustain rural Ethiopians in their poverty, let alone generated growth, food security and poverty reduction. In a two-pronged attack on rural poverty in Ethiopia, therefore, the PSNP injects cash into a moribund agrarian economy, while PASDEP promotes market chains and export crops that will generate further cash income. This is a major move away from a ‘survivalist’ preoccupation with growing food for subsistence and delivering food aid for survival when food production is inadequate. Whether it will succeed only time will tell. This paper explores the linkages between social protection interventions and support to small farmer development in Ethiopia. The paper is divided into six main sections. Following this Introduction, Section 2 argues that agricultural policies and social protection policies in Ethiopia have become increasingly convergent and synergistic in recent years. Section 3 explores the paradoxical relationship of small farmers to land, which is regarded by the government not only as a key productive asset but also as a fundamental ‘safety net’, but could also be interpreted as contributing to the ‘poverty trap’ that millions of Ethiopians find themselves in. Section 4 briefly reviews recent developments in agricultural policy in Ethiopia, focusing on the recent drive for agricultural commercialisation as encapsulated in the shift from ‘ADLI’ to ‘PASDEP’. Section 5 analyses the components of the ‘Food Security Programme’ in detail, with empirical evidence of the impact of the Productive Safety Net Programme (PSNP) on agriculture. Section 6 discusses recent innovative interventions that build linkages between social protection and agriculture, such as weather-indexed drought insurance and the design of an ‘integrated drought risk management plan’ and a commodity exchange for Ethiopia. Section 7 concludes. Page 2 of 18 2 Agriculture and social protection in Ethiopia: complementarity or convergence? The Government of Ethiopia’s policies for agriculture and social protection follow a trajectory that can be interpreted as a kind of convergence. In the past, policies of ‘agricultural promotion’ and interventions that might now be labelled ‘social protection’ were more or less distinct, linked only by the fact that social protection – or more accurately, safety nets or humanitarian relief – was triggered as a response to agricultural failure. When harvests failed, safety nets intervened to protect farming families against the severest consequences. This sequential separation can be conceptualised as a ‘seasonal policy timeline’, with agricultural policy (such as inputs provision) delivered during the farming season and safety nets (typically food aid or food-for-work) delivered during the ‘hungry season’ several months later. In this sense, agricultural policy and social protection policy are mirror images: the more effectively farming fills household granaries, the smaller the annual appeal for humanitarian assistance, but several million Ethiopians need ‘emergency relief’ for several months every year to see them through to the next harvest, and in years of catastrophic crop failure this figure rises to 12 or 14 million. Terminology matters: the phrase ‘social protection’ is not yet current in Ethiopia, perhaps because of its close association with ‘social welfare’ – and by extension, ‘dependency’ – to which the government is strongly opposed because it believes in self-reliance at household and community levels, especially in rural areas where most people are either farming or have relatives farming or otherwise working for them. Instead, Ethiopia has decades of experience with ‘safety nets’, signifying transitory support mechanisms of last resort (rather than institutionalised permanent welfare systems), and more recently it has introduced ‘productive safety nets’ (as discussed below), emphasising the synergies that the government aims to achieve between ‘livelihood protection’ and ‘livelihood promotion’. There have been some unintended negative interactions between the two sets of interventions. For instance, public works projects are often implemented during the months leading up to the next harvest – at the peak of the hungry season, but also at the peak of the farming season. The competition for household labour between public works and the household farm often forces farmers to neglect their fields, compromising the next harvest and perpetuating the cycle of agricultural under-performance and rural food insecurity. The main policy response has been to tinker with design and implementation modalities: mainly to try to time public works better, and there have been suggestions (not yet implemented to our knowledge) that works should be undertaken before the farming season starts, with payments deferred until the ‘hungry season’. (This was proposed as long ago as 1993, in the Directives in support of the National Policy on Disaster Prevention and Management: “coupons, in lieu of wages, could be redeemed immediately or at a future date”.) A more radical recommendation would be to de-link the delivery of social protection from any labour requirement altogether. The asset creation benefits of public works are too inadequate to justify the conscription of cheap labour, while the poorest and most vulnerable households are typically labour-constrained, rather than underemployed with ‘surplus labour’ to allocate to public works. More recently, the positive linkages between agricultural policy and social protection policy have become increasingly recognised, in general and in Ethiopia, and there are attempts in many countries to achieve synergies between the two. But recognition that positive linkages might exist is not new. Thinking on ‘linking relief and development’ in Ethiopia since the early 1990s has concentrated on efforts to generate agricultural growth through safety nets, by using public works programmes to simultaneously transfer food rations (a classic ‘consumption smoothing’ safety net objective) and also (in theory) to construct useful economic infrastructure such as roads (to integrate markets for farmers and traders), or to subsidise agricultural activities such as vegetable gardens (promoting production of secondary food crops for both consumption and sale). Faced with ‘low input, low output’ agriculture, it might seem logical for policy-makers to assume that farmers face binding input constraints, and that the solution from both an agricultural and a Page 3 of 18 social protection perspective lies in the intensification of smallholder production to maximise yields from small plots of farmland. This thinking underpins many interventions that can be described as ‘productivity-enhancing safety nets’ (Devereux 1999), such as Sasakawa Global 2000, which delivers fertiliser and seeds to farmers on a revolving credit basis and has had some success in raising crop yields in some places – including parts of Ethiopia – at some times. Unfortunately, revolving credit schemes depend on reliable repayment and do not cope well with variability in production and repayments. Global 2000 projects are prone to collapse whenever a bad harvest undermines farmers’ ability to repay their loans. In Ethiopia, a perverse outcome occurred in the 1990s, when farmers were encouraged to take on inputs packages as loans, and were actually imprisoned when drought shocks left them unable to repay these loans after a failed harvest. This experience raises broader questions about the logic of providing social assistance or income-generating support to poor households in the form of (even zero-interest) loans, which could simply leave them indebted and worse off than before – another example of a ‘negative synergy’ between agricultural and social protection objectives. In fact, efforts at achieving synergies in both directions (promoting agricultural growth in Ethiopia through ‘productivity-enhancing’ safety nets, or achieving social protection through risk-reducing agriculture) have been persistently compromised by the instability of the natural environment, especially fluctuations in rainfall on which smallholder agriculture depends. Neither investments in agriculture nor investments in social protection appear capable of dealing with this risk. Irrigation might seem a logical way to proceed, but the scale of the need is so vast and the available moisture in the highlands is so low that large-scale irrigation has never emerged as a realistic option, though it is repeatedly recommended. 3 ‘Land politics’ and social protection in Ethiopia Successive Ethiopian regimes have located the source of Ethiopia’s economic stagnation and vulnerability in the agriculture sector, yet they have also looked to smallholder agriculture as the potential source of economic growth, household and national food security and poverty reduction. In 2000, Prime Minister Meles Zenawi captured this ambivalence succinctly when he said: “The agricultural sector remains our Achilles heel and source of vulnerability. Nonetheless, we remain convinced that agricultural based development remains the only source of hope for Ethiopia.” At the heart of this ambivalence is the politics of land. The overthrow of Emperor Haile Selassie following the 1974 famine signalled the abrupt ending of an essentially feudal system in Ethiopian agriculture. Colonel Mengistu’s Derg regime believed that unequal landholdings and exploitative labour relations based on sharecropping explained Ethiopia’s persistent vulnerability to famine, as well as constituting a gross social injustice. The Derg military dictatorship used its unfettered power to force a radical agrarian transformation on rural Ethiopia. Between 1976 and 1991, all farmland in the highlands was confiscated by the state and redistributed equally per capita within rural communities. This radical land redistribution was motivated by both egalitarian and efficiency concerns. The intention was not only to break the power of the landlords over the peasants, but to give all rural households the means to achieve sustainable increases in agricultural productivity and rural incomes (Devereux et al., 2005). Importantly, land was conceptualised as a safety net for rural households by the Derg (a view that is shared by Meles Zenawi’s EPRDF government). As long as rural families enjoyed guaranteed access to land, they retained the potential to generate a subsistence livelihood, and in this sense the Derg’s land redistribution can be seen as a crude form of social protection. Motivated by its socialist egalitarian ideology, the Derg also implemented agricultural policies such as state farms, villagisation and forced resettlement, all of which failed to generate the intended growth in agricultural productivity and were later abandoned. It is no coincidence that the Derg presided over an even worse famine, in 1984, than the famine of 1974 that had paved its accession to power. The land redistribution remains as the Derg’s lasting impact on Ethiopian agriculture. After the Derg was overthrown in 1991, the EPRDF government under Prime Minister Meles Zenawi reaffirmed the Derg’s commitment to land equality, and Meles has vociferously resisted Page 4 of 18
no reviews yet
Please Login to review.